Outline:
01st Introduction
02nd The Laissez-faire liberalism
03rd The Ordoliberalism
04th The popular capitalism
05th The welfare state
06th The overall control
07th The Planning
08th The concerted action
09th The nationalisation of the key industries
10th The market socialism
11th The Yugoslav model
12th The centrally administered economy
09th The nationalisation of the key industries
The conception of the nationalisation of
the key industries, as represented by the German social democracies until the
Bad Godesberger program of 1959, went much further in
the criticism of the market economy (capitalism) than the order conceptions
discussed so far and approached much closer to the concept of a state planned
economy.
Of course the social democrats also shared
the criticism from a social point of view until that time. The way as, for
example, the criticism was raised from the representatives of the popular
capitalism against a pure market economy, which was rooted in the statement
that the social concerns of the general public were insufficiently considered
and that the income distribution would develop to the disadvantage of the
employees.
The social democrats also criticised the
allocation results of the market, for example, as they have been imposed by the
representatives of a planning in France for a long time, whereby the main focus
of criticism was set on the possibilities of the market failure and the market
deficits.
But the social democrats did not stay with
this criticism. Just like the old liberals had a deep aversion to any kind of
state interference on the economy, the social democrats were convinced that the
private property and the pursuit of profit of the entrepreneurs constituted the
root cause for the determined disproportions and thus had to be regarded as
something bad per se. Thus, the entire commercially invested capital would have
to be nationalised.
For what reasons, though, did the social
democrats confine themselves to the demand to nationalise nevertheless not all
enterprises, but only the key industries until the Bad Godesberger
program? The reason for this was the fact that the social democrats professed a
liberal socialism at a very early stage already and, moreover, the negative
experiences that socialism had created in the communist countries (in Russia)
with planned economy systems.
On the one hand, a dictatorship of the
proletariat, as propagated and practiced by the Russian communists, was
rejected. On the other hand, it was feared that in the case of a total
nationalisation of all enterprises the state planning authority could acquire
so much power, that it could escape the control by the parliament.
Therefore, the social democrats demanded
only the nationalisation of the so-called key industries. One was also
convinced that, even with this restriction in the nationalisation to a few
economy sectors, the actual aim of this order conception could be achieved:
namely the orientation of production to the needs of the people, especially the
employees.
Now, what was meant by key industries? By
this term the energy industries, in particular coal production, furthermore
steel production as well as the banking sector was understood. Thus, by this
concept not only industries in the narrower sense are covered, since only steel
is produced by industrial methods. At the time, the energy industry was limited
to coal production that was the mining, and the banking system was and is of
the sector of services.
Now one was convinced that even with a
nationalisation of only the key industries, a control of all markets could be
guaranteed. For the production and consumption of almost all goods actually
energy would be needed. A demand for steel
exists - or existed at that time - particularly in the automobile and machine
industry; machines, though, are in turn used for the production of most of the
goods, they represent a part of the production capacity.
Finally, the banking industry comes into
play thereby that almost all enterprises need loans which are loaned from the
banks. For the large corporations comes in addition that they buy their capital
mainly on the capital markets and that the banks provide help in this regard.
But it is precisely the large corporations which in the opinion of the
Socialists are responsible for the lack of orientation of the production to the
needs of the people.
By taking control of bank lending and the
allocation of steel and energy by a nationalisation of the key industries, the
state was now in a position to align the entire production of an economy with
the ideas of the government.
The possibility that there is policy
failure besides market failure and that the policy failure can be greater than
the market failure in the concrete individual case is not considered in this
conception. At the same time, it is overlooked that a bureaucratic system is
highly inefficient and thus inferior to a system of free enterprises.
The bureaucracy lacks incentives to strive
for the most efficient solution for the production of goods, the bureaucrat
does not have to pay for the losses caused by him and is therefore also ready
for risky tasks; he also does not receive the profits he has generated. If,
however, losses and profits are calculated by political means, it is generally
the politicians and not the bureaucrats who make and implement the individual
concrete decisions.
10th The market socialism
The order conception of the market
socialism developed by Oskar Lange differs from the previously approached
conceptions of socialism particularly in the rationale. His aim is to develop a
theory of the state planning of a socialist national economy.
Starting point of his considerations are
the results of the recent theory of welfare. If one proceeds from the welfare
theory developed by Vilfredo Pareto, the welfare optimum of a national economy
is determined by the tangential point of the transformation curve with a
collective indifference curve. Let us consider this correlation by the
following graphic:
On the coordinates, the quantities that
are to be produced of two goods (bundles of goods) x1 and x2 are drawn. The red
curve represents the transformation curve, which indicates which goods
combinations can be produced with the given resources. The blue curves render
the collective indifference curve, which connects all the combinations of
goods, which guarantee an equal high welfare.
The intended combination of goods must firstly
be at (or if need be below) the transformation curve, since only such
combinations are possible at all. Secondly, from the number of the possible
combinations should those be selected which guarantee the highest welfare.
Since the indifference curves are the further distant from the coordinate
origin, the greater is the welfare which reflects this curve, thus exactly that
point of the diagram fulfils this condition, at which a collective indifference
curve is tangent to the transformation curve.
Those combinations of goods, which lie on
the lowest indifference curve and cut the transformation curve but are not
tangent to this, are possible, though do not express the highest possible
welfare; those goods combinations, which lie on an indifference curve which
does absolutely not touch the transformation curve, would indeed indicate a
higher welfare than the tangential point, but they are not realisable because
they are not at all on the transformation curve.
Now the traditional welfare theory has
shown that in a market economy under very specific conditions the welfare
potential is just being aimed by trend. One of the two most important
conditions is the requirement that there are no external costs present, thus
all costs incurred by a national economy are also borne by the enterprises
which incur such costs. On the other hand, complete competition has to prevail
on all markets and on both sides of the market.
If we assume, for the sake of
simplicity, that there are no external
costs, it is relatively easy to prove that, at the presence of complete
competition and in equilibrium precisely the goods combination is realised
which corresponds to the tangential point of the transformation curve with a
collective indifference curve and which thus guarantees a welfare optimum.
In a first step, it is proven that
whenever the entrepreneurs strive to expand the production of their goods until
the marginal costs correspond to the given prices, in equilibrium the marginal
rate of the transformation corresponds to the marginal cost ratios and these to
the price ratios. If complete competition prevails, the entrepreneurs will
maximise their profit namely just when this marginal- cost pricing rule is met.
In a second step, it is proven that
households maximise their benefit precisely when the marginal rate of
substitution corresponds to the price ratio of the goods. If two values are
equal to a third one, they are also equal to each other. If both the marginal
rate of substitution and the transformation correspond to the goods price ratio,
then corresponds also the marginal rate of the substitution necessarily to the
marginal rate of the transformation. Since the equality of both marginal rates
constitutes the requirement for a welfare optimum, it is thus proved that in
the case of complete competition (and avoidance of external costs) the welfare
optimum is realised.
Now, Oskar Lange assumes that this requirement
is not fulfilled in reality. The markets show monopolies and oligopolies, still
not all economic costs are charged to the causative enterprises. For these
reasons it must be assumed that the free market does not head for an optimal
solution in reality.
Now, here starts the solution suggested by
Oskar Lange. If an optimal solution could be achieved in the case of complete competition,
then the optimality can also be achieved when the production managers are urged
to behave like free entrepreneurs in competitive markets and to extend their
production until the marginal costs correspond to the goods prices. The
enterprises get nationalised and the production managers are bound by
directives.
But this model works only if the prices
set by the state reflect the scarcity of the goods and thus correspond to the
equilibrium prices on the markets. Since the state can not know the scarcity
relations in advance at the assumption of the consumer sovereignty, it is
necessary to simulate the balance mechanism. The state authority assumes any
prices and varies these as long as supply and demand do not correspond, whereby
an excess supply must be answered with price reductions, and an excess demand
must be answered with price increases, though.
To criticism, though, it must be noted
that this concept neglects all internal administrative coordination problems.
Within a market economy, entrepreneurs keep the marginal-cost pricing rule out
of self interest. Entrepreneurs are trying to maximise their profits, and this
is precisely the case when the entrepreneurs observe the marginal-cost pricing
rule.
For the production managers, this rule
constitutes initially only an instruction and it has to be checked whether respectively
under what conditions the production managers have an interest in passing over
these instructions. Since the superordinate authorities do not know the trend
of the marginal costs per se, but are dependent on the data provided by the
production managers, the possibility must be expected that the production
managers try to conceal the amount of marginal costs.
Only a theory which, on the one hand,
describes the individual motives of the production managers and, on the other
hand, explains the incentive systems operating within the bureaucracy, can
clarify whether and under which conditions it can be expected that the
marginal-cost pricing rule is observed by the production managers also.
11th The Yugoslav model
A special variant of a socialist planned
economy is found in the model which Tito had realised in the immediate period
after the Second World War in Yugoslavia. While in most socialist models the
criticism of the capitalist system led thereto that the commercial private
property was laid in the hands of the state, thus was nationalised; in the
Yugoslav model, a socialisation of commercial private property takes place, in
which the previous private property was transferred into a property of the
respective workforce of the individual enterprises. One was of the opinion that
the deficiencies of the monopolistic capitalism could be overcome by
transferring the production capital into the hands of the workforce.
As with the concepts of the French
planning in other respects it is trusted largely in the effectiveness of the
markets. Existing market imperfections shall be overcome and corrected by means
of indicative macroeconomic plans and by state subsidy policy. No interest is
levied on the capital invested in the enterprises and the production credits
granted to the enterprises, since the socialist idea assumes that only labour
would create value and that therefore only the work input but not the capital contribution
justifies an income reference.
It must be noted critically that
disincentives emanate from this system. For example, leads the deactivation of
the capital market mechanism to an inefficient use of resources. Like every
price in a market-economy system, does the interest not only have the function
of paying a compensation to the saver for temporary renunciation of
consumption, but has to ensure primarily that the scarce capital is used
efficiently, thus flows in each case into the productions in which the capital generates
the highest possible return.
This allocative task is no longer required
simply because one passes from a pure market economy to a socialist system.
Also in a socialist state applies that capital as a factor of production is
scarce and growth losses occur if the efficient use of capital is not ensured.
For a bureaucracy it is quite impossible to recognise the sectors in which the
capital investment occurs optimal, at least if it is intended to adapt the
production to the wishes of the consumers. If the interest rate is zero, also
such productions are expanded that promise a lower capital yield than it
corresponds to the interest rate.
On the one hand, a too low interest rate
leads to an excess demand for loans, the government authorities have to
allocate the too scarce capital; in the absence of proper efficiency criteria,
political criteria are applied which lead to inefficient productions.
On the other hand, it must be feared that
where capital is used inefficiently, where additional production capacities are
built which do not correspond to consumer wishes, the individual holdings will
have to be closed sooner or later because of insolvency and thereby capital is
destroyed. The result is a reduction in economic growth.
A second deficiency of the Yugoslav model
is that the labour market also becomes imbalanced. It is a serious mistake to
think that if the interests of the enterprises are put in the hands of the
respective workforce that then the interests of the entire workforce would be
represented best possible automatically. In this way, the problem of
unemployment can not be solved satisfactorily.
The interests of employed workers often
deviate from the interests of the not yet employed workers. The workforce
represents only the interests of the employed workers; for example, it has to
be feared that the workforce will also impose such wage increases which will
lead thereto that not all workers will find employment. It is therefore
overlooked here that the workforce can not represent the interests of the
unemployed workers.
12th The centrally administered economy
In conclusion, let us turn to the order
conception of the centrally administered economy, the antipode of a pure market
economy; we follow the classification made by Walter Eucken.
Representatives of a pure central
administration system were, on the one side, the communists in the former
Eastern bloc, although it must be stated indeed that Karl Marx had dealt
extensively with the alleged weaknesses of a capitalist economic system, but
made very few thoughts about how a Communist Economy would work, on which way
the allocation would be regulated after the markets had been eliminated.
Karl Marx was too much convinced that an
economy that is liberated from the profit interests of the capitalists, and in
which capital is used, could produce goods in abundance and therefore was able
to satisfy all the needs of the population; in view of this expected abundance,
the problems of an efficient allocation of the resources faded into the
background.
A centrally administered economy was
furthermore realised in the western states during the wars, but here it was
less a desired arrangement, but rather because there was no other possibility
regarded to allow market regulations during a war. A war economy is
characterised by a particularly severe scarcity of material resources. The war
aims and the supply of the armies with the goods essential to the war effort
have a clear priority. Here, a market economical guidance would only interfere.
A centrally administered economy is
characterised by the fact that all fundamental economic decisions are based on
a central governmental plan. This determination does not say anything about the
size of the central planning authority initially. This depends basically on the
size of the entire national economy. In large industrial societies, an
extensive planning authority is required which is spread on numerous levels
which are structured hierarchically.
A central authority formulates the basic
aims of the planning and determines the allocation of scarce resources to the
individual large economic sectors. Subordinate bodies specify these plans
according to the exact specifications of the central. These receive detailed
instructions, which are passed top down. However, since the central planning
requires a variety of individual facts which can only be determined at the
lowest level, the data has to be collected before the planning aims are
defined, whereat the data flow occurs here from the lowest to the highest
department.
In contrast to the planning and the
Yugoslav model, there is not an indicative planning but an imperative planning
present. In the case of the centrally administered economy, the central does
not confine itself to specify the allocation of the scarce resources, but it
defines bindingly the individual usage types of the scarce resources.
In the pure form of a centrally administered
economy, the planning is carried out up to the permitted consumption of the
individual households. To them, the consumer goods are allocated in form of
ration coupons (e.g. food ration cards). Formally, the employees receive indeed
income as in the market economy, while prices for the individual goods are
still fixed which must be paid from the income for the consumption of consumer
goods. But in contrast to the free market can the household only buy the goods
and in the quantities for which it has ration coupons. Here, the prices do not
have the function, unlike as in market economies, of indicating the scarcity of
the individual goods and resources and thereby to direct production.
So far about the presentation of the
centrally administered economy in its purest form. Two variants have been
developed in the course of the implementation of this order conception: on the
one hand, there is a state planned economy with freedom of consumption, on the
other hand there is a decentralisation of the planning authority with more or
less large decision-making scopes for the subordinate planning authorities.
This easing of the state planning economy
occurred mainly due to the competition of the systems which had developed
between the western-oriented economies and the Eastern bloc of communism since
the fifties of the last century. Thus Khrushchev introduced a limited freedom
of consumption in the course of a general liberalisation of the economy in 1953
after the death of Stalin.
Later, mainly in the eighties of the last
century, Gorbachev initiated a major decentralisation of the planning, the top
planning authorities confined themselves to set the most important fundamental
aims of the planning, while the subordinate planning authorities were given broad
scope for the decision-making.
The question, whether in the context of a
centrally administered economy an efficient planning could be carried out at
all, was discussed controversially for a long time. Walter Eucken was still of
the opinion that in this economic system no rational economic planning was
possible at all. A fixing of the prices for the individual consumer goods was
only possible if the scarcity and thus the prices of the individual production
factors are known. The scarcity of the production factors and thus the
appropriate level of the factor prices, though, can in turn be determined only
if the prices of the end products and with them the exact demand for these
goods are known. Only a market economy system was capable of solving this
allocation problem satisfactorily by a simultaneous determination of all prices
- of the final products as well as of the production factors.
As a further argument for the
impossibility of a central efficient economic calculation it was pointed out
during the period directly after the Second World War that the computer systems
known at the time were not capable at all of calculating equation systems with
functions of higher degree. As is well known, in the production theory we
assume Cobb-Douglas production functions which are determined by non-linear
parameters.
In response to this criticism, K. Paul
Hensel, a follower of Walter Eucken, had tried to show that a rational economic
calculation is possible within the framework of a centrally administered
economy, namely thereby that the planning is confined to quantity variables.
Furthermore, on the one hand, the
capacities of the computer systems have been increased many times over
meanwhile. On the other hand, the development of the concept of the 'linear
programming' has attempted to display the production processes by means of
linear production functions and thus to increase the computability of the
production processes.
It must be critically stated, though, that
in all models of a governmental bureaucratic economy all coordination problems
are disregarded. It is assumed as naturally that the instructions of the
authorities are followed by the subordinate authorities a hundred per cent.
The experience shows de facto that also
bureaucrats are guided by own interests, that they often also have sufficient
power against the politicians to circumvent the instructions. It is one thing to describe the ideal-type functioning
of an economic system and a completely different thing to ask for the specific
procedures of this system.
The theory of state planned economy has
been confined mainly to the idealistic consideration. The criticism of the
models of a state planned economy has pointed out that not only in market
economies, but in all real systems, especially also in the systems of a state
planned economy, failures and shortcomings set in repeatedly which cause the
result of the real economic process to diverge more or less from the ideal-type
results.
These real difficulties are to be expected
especially, if the centrally administered economy allows freedom of
consumption. This fact raises doubts as to the efficiency of state planning,
since nowadays an economic order without freedom of consumption is not
conceivable in any remaining communist state.